Supplier Induced Demand is a
contentious issue even among health economists and runs counter to the
“normative implications of conventional models of demand and supply” (McGuire,
2000). It occurs when there is asymmetry of information between supplier and consumer. In Health
Economics, the supplier is typically a physician and the consumer is the
patient. The patient has a principle-agent relationship with the physician. The
Principle, or the patient, relies on the agent, the physician, to act in his or
her best interests regarding medical care, given that they are better informed
than them. This allows the agent, who is also the supplier of the medical care,
much freedom over the level of healthcare that they can provide and therefore
induce unnecessarily too much medical care to their own financial gain.
Milton I. Roemer put
forward the first theory of supplier-induced demand in the healthcare market
back in 1959 and 1961, following what he saw as a result of the Hill- Burton
Act, also known as The Hospital Survey and Construction Act of 1946. This Act made it easier for
Federal funding for building not-for-profit hospitals, so as to achieve a ratio
of 4.5 hospital beds per 1,000 people (Brinker and Walker 1962). Roemer noticed
a community in upstate New York
looking for funding for a new hospital, despite having a hospital already
working at 70% capacity. When the community received funding for the additional
hospital, Roemer expected the second hospital to be empty but to his
astonishment the second hospital, within a few months, operated at a 70%
capacity also. This observation prompted Roemer to write an academic paper in
which he stated “in an insured population, a bed built is a bed filled” (Roemer
and Shain, 1959) or, to put it more generally, faced with shock to equilibrium
(increase supply), health providers respond by ‘inducing demand’ (shifting the
demand curve) for their services.
Supplier Induced Demand and Caesarean
Deliveries
Roemer’s observation has spawned a
great debate regarding the presence of supplier induced leading to many papers
and studies by academics around the world. One leading paper on supplier
induced demand is that of Gruber and Owings (1996). Gruber and Owings studied
the increase in caesarean section delivery in the US between 1970 and 1982 when
fertility rates fell by 13.5%. Before this fall in fertility, child births
comprised approximately half of all obstetricians’ and gynaecologists’ income.
This fall in fertility rates resulted in an exogenous shock to their incomes of
about 6.75%, not an insignificant amount. During this time in fertility
decline, the rate of c-sections rose immensely. C-section birth rates doubled
between 1970 and 1975 and had doubled again by 1984. Was this exclusively down
to supplier induced demand or were there other factors involved?
While it would
be quite easy to blame this increase solely on supplier induced demand it is
clearly not true. There are a number of factors that increased the rate of
caesarean deliveries. One factor, and often the
most cited reason, that may have contributed to the rise in the number of
c-sections was the rise of technology in childbirth process. Increased use of
technology that monitored foetal distress came into widespread use in the
1970s. 70% of deliveries in 1970 were reported without complications. This had
fallen to 39% in 1984 (Shiono, McNellis, and Rhoads, 1987), no doubt due to the
increased use of technology.
Another Factor, in the rising c-section rate, could have been the changing
legal environment at the time. Marieskind (1959) reports the most frequent
reason given by obstetrician-gynaecologists in
choosing c-section delivery is the fear of a malpractice suit against them. She
further cites the National Association of Insurance Commissioners report stating
the obstetricians-gynaecologists, in the period 1975-1976, were ten times more
likely to face a suit of malpractice than any other physicians. In another
paper studying c-section rates in California ,
Main et al (2011) found obstetrician-gynaecologists today
were among the medical specialties most likely to face a malpractice claim, and
they “have a higher risk of an indemnity payment exceeding $1 million”.
In addition to these factors, Gruber and Owings (1996) state, that
during the time studied (1970-1984), c-section delivery was associated with
better health outcomes for both child and mother among physicians although,
ever since it is generally agreed that vaginal delivery is better.
Additionally, once c-section is the generally accepted way of treating certain
types of births, it is very hard for obstetrician-gynaecologists to revert back
to how they once did things and still convince themselves that they were
providing the same level of care.
It is also
important to look at supplier induced demand as a proponent of this large
increase in the c-section rate. No doubt the incentives for supplier induced
demand to physicians were there. Physician charges for c-section deliveries
were $2,053 in 1989, compared to $1,492 for normal deliveries. No such data exists
for the 1970s but Marieskind (1979) stated that the average difference between
c-section delivery and vaginal delivery was 40%, similar to 1989
reimbursements. This difference in price was not justified by physician factor
inputs. In fact, Keeler and Brodie (1993) found that “costs to the
physician of a vaginal delivery vary widely, the reviewed evidence showed them
to be similar to C-sections, on average” and that the workload for vaginal
delivery is greater than a caesarean. Gruber and Owings (1996) claim they tended to be
more efficient, often taking less time than normal birth and could be scheduled
in advance. It is not surprising perhaps to notice. This price differential as
well as time savings provide a large incentive for the physician. Main et al
(2011) also came to the same conclusion and, continued on stating “a vaginal
delivery after a c-section delivery typically are long and as a result have a
lower economic reimbursement”.
When Grubers and
Owing looked at the data for c-section delivery between 1970 and 1984 they
found a strong correlation between fertility declines and increase in c-section
delivery rates: a 10% drop in fertility
translated to almost a 1% in the rate of c-section delivery. Furthermore, there
is a
positive relationship
between the log
of obstetrician-gynaecologists
density and the
probability of c-section
delivery: a 10% increase
in the obstetrician-gynaecologists density raises
the probability of a caesarean
by .6 percentage points. Not an insignificant
relationship. They also found that the result of a 10% fall in fertility among
the privately-insured population resulted in a rise in c-section deliveries of
over 1.6 percentage points while a similar fall in fertility among the
uninsured (and as a result those less likely to pay) only resulted in a .65
percentage point rise. Furthermore, they state that the 13.5 % fall in
fertility only accounted to a 16% rise in c-sections.
In weighing up
their data on the c-section delivery rise between 1970 and 1984, Gruber and
Owings came to the conclusion that “physicians overused caesarean delivery
relative to the level that would be chosen by a financially disinterested
medical provider” adding although
inducement took place the “magnitude… was small”.

Supplier Induced Demand among General Physicians
Most of the research done into
supplier induced demand has been based around the actions of physicians.
Madden, Nolan and Nolan (2005) focused on the Irish physicians during a time
when physician’s payment for medical card holders changed from fee-per-service
to capitation. This change from fee-per-service to capitation was highly
influenced by Tussing’s 1983 paper on which seemed to show favour for demand
inducement by physicians. This exogenous change in physician allowed them to
examine the extent to which utilization of
physician services in Ireland
is influenced by physician reimbursement scheme.
Madden et al., found that the
differentials between visiting rates of medical card holders and the rest of
the population did not narrow when the physician reimbursement scheme was
changed “as might have been anticipated if supplier induced demand played a
major role”.
Other studies into
demand-inducement by physicians include Willensky and Rossiter (1983). They
studied the significance of ambulatory visits in the US in 1977. They found that 39% of
all ambulatory visits and, 45% of all dollars spent on ambulatory visits were
initiated by the physician. If supplier induced demand were present, ambulatory
visits were sure to be one area in which it could be exploited.
Willensky and Rossiter (1983) found that even in areas
where inducement was exhibited it’s presence was small. This finding regarding
demand-inducement was consistant with many of Wwnnburg’s findings also (Wennberg
and Gittelson, 1973; Wennberg 1978;
Wennberg et al. 1982).
Small Area Variations
Small area variations is often held
up as evidence for induced demand among physicians. This has been quite
sufficiently dealt with by a number of studies including Richardson and Peacock
(2006), Wennburg (1988) and Mulley (2009). Richardson and Peacock cite a long
list of factors that affect physician decision making including training, peer
behaviour, conference attendance, personal temperament and experience, as well
as infrastructural capacity to undertake further intensive investigation.
Wennburg (1988)
cites huge professional uncertainty in the medical world fro such great
variations among regions. He claims that professional uncertainty rather
than consensus about the scientific basis of clinical practice is emerging as
the dominating reality”. He lays the blame at the feet of expert panels who
have failed to reach an agreed consensus on appropriate practice in treating
patients. This failure of consensus has led to “validity of many specific
theories physicians hold on appropriate practice” and no real efficiency and
homogeneous procedures among physicians to common illnesses over large
areas.
Mulley (2009)
cites that healthcare professionals become accustomed to standard policies that
have been shaped by local capacity and are often very surprised to learn that
policies are different elsewhere.
Conclusions
Despite many bold claims about
supplier induced demand in the health sector, there isn’t much evidence to
suggest that it is a large problem. True evidence for supplier induced
demand seems to be sporadic at best. Richardson
and Peacock (2006) state that most common explanations of supplier induced
demand in the healthcare industry “are only partially convincing”. The general
belief among health economists is one summed up by Hurley and Labelle (1995) when they state “physicians
can
induce demand for their services, they sometimes do induce demand, but that such
responses are neither automatic nor unconstrained.....bitches”.
Bibliography:
Brinker
P.A. and Walker B., (1962). The
Hill-Burton Act: 1948-1954. The Review of Economics and
Statistics. Vol. 44, No. 2 pp.
208-212
Gruber,
J. and Owings, M. (1996). Physician
Financial Incentives and Caesarean Section Delivery. The RAND
Journal of Economics. Vol. 27,
No. 1, pp. 99-123
Hurley, J., and Labelle, R. (1995) “Relative fees and the
utilization of physicians’ services in Canada ”, Health Economics, No.4, pp. 419-438
Keeler E.B. AND
Brodie, M. (1993).
"Economic Incentives in
the Choice Between
Vaginal Delivery and
Cesarean Section."
The Milbank Quarterly, Vol.
71, pp. 365-404.
Marieskind, H.I. (1979)
"An Evaluation of
Caesarean Section in
the United States."
Final Report Submitted
to the Department of
Health, Education and
Welfare Office of
the Assistant Secretary
for Planning and
Evaluation/Health. Washington , D.C. : GPO.
Madden, D., Nolan, A.,
Nolan, B (2005).: GP reimbursement and visiting behaviour in Ireland . Health Econ. 14, pp. 1047–1060
Main
EK, Morton CH, Hopkins D, Giuliani G, Melsop K and Gould JB (2011). Cesarean Deliveries,
Outcomes, and Opportunities for Change in California : Toward a Public Agenda for
Maternity Care Safety and Quality. Palo
Alto , CA : CMQCC.
McGuire, T.G. (2000). Physician Agency. In: Culyer A.J. and
Newhouse J.P. Handbook of Health
Economics, Part 1. New York :
Elsevier Science pp.462-
517
Mulley A.G. (2009) “Inconvenient truths about supplier
induced demand and unwarranted variation in medical practice” British Medical Journal 2009
Vol. 339 No. 1 pp. 1007-1009
Roemer M. I. and Shain
M., (1959). "Hospital
Utilization Under Insurance", Hospital Monograph Series,
No. 6, Amer. Hos. Assoc., Chicago.
Shiono, PH.,
McNellis, D., and Rhoads, G.G. (1987) "Reasons
for the Rising
Cesarean Delivery Rates,
1978-1984." Obstetrics &
Gynecology, Vol. 69, pp. 696-700.
Tussing, A. (1983). Physician-Induced Demand for Medical
Care: Irish General Practitioners. The
Economic and Social Review, 14 (3), 225-247.
Wennberg, J.E. and Gittelsohn,
A. (1973). Small Area Variations in
Health Care Delivery. Science
Vol.183: pp. 102-8.
Wennberg, J.E. (1978). An Epidemiological Perspective on the
Problem
Of Supplier-Insured Demand: The
Case of Surgery and Surgical
Second Opinions. In Physicians and Financial Incentives,
Health
Care Financing Administration; Washington .
Wennberg, J.E., Barnes, B.A. and
Zubkoff, M. (1982). Professional
Uncertainty and the Problem of
Supplier-Induced Demand. Social
Science and Medicine Vol.246 No. 4, pp. 120-34.
Wennberg, J.E. (1988), ‘Improving the medical decision
making process’, Health Affairs, Vol.
7, No. 1, pp 99-106.
Wilensky G.R. and Rossiter L.F. (1983) “The Relative Importance of Physician-Induced
Demand in the Demand for Medical Care” The Milbank Memorial Fund
Quarterly. Health and Society, Vol. 61, No. 2, pp. 252-277
No comments:
Post a Comment